VARIATIONS ON THE WELFARE STATE
Giuseppe Pennisi
In 2014, two major negotiations will be closely
intertwined in their respective agendas: a) the revision of the European
Monetary Union (EMU) already started with a number of piece meal changes to the
twenty years old Maastricht Treaty; and b) the beginning, hopefully, of the
international operational discussions on the establishment of a Transatlantic
Partnership and the drafting of a pertinent Agreement. Each of them will have
an impact of the European welfare state model, which is now based on a high
level of taxation to finance, by and large, an extended income support system. Fifteen years ago, a well known Italian
economist Pier Luigi Ciocca (then Deputy Director General of the Bank of Italy)
raised a very pertinent question in the foreword of the collective book Disoccupazione di Fine Secolo (BollatiBoringhieri, 1997) if Europe
could remain competitive in the world area with a tax pressure equivalent to
42% of GDP when in North America, Japan and Australia, the tax pressure is
around un third of GDP and in the new emerging countries is about one forth. In
the last decade and a half, the situation has not improved; i.e. in Italy now
the tax pressure approaches 48% of GDP. European competitiveness has
dramatically slowed down in all European countries that have not implemented
drastic reforms. An updating and a revision of the Maastricht Treaty is
required If the euro area wants to wake up from a
long lethargy and become dynamic. In a future Transatlantic Partnership, there
is no room for major differences in tax pressure and welfare cost. Italy may
have an important role in both negotiations because in the second semester of
2014, it chairs the European Union (EU) Council and associated bodies.
No doubt, as recently purported in a joint paper by
Inci Otker Robe (IMF) and Anca Maria Podpiera (World Bank) – The Social Impact of Financial Crises-
Evidence from the Global Financial Crises , World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper No. 6703- the financial
crisis that has hit the world economy since
2008 has transformed the lives of many individuals and families, even in
advanced countries, and especially in Europe where millions of people fell, or
are at risk of falling, into poverty and exclusion. For most regions and income
groups in developing countries, progress to meet the Millennium Development
Goals by 2015 has slowed and income distribution has worsened for a number of
countries. Countries hardest hit by the crisis lost more than a decade of
economic time. As the efforts to strengthen the financial systems and improve
the resilience of the global financial system continue around the world, the
challenge for policy makers is to incorporate the lessons from the failures to
take into consideration the complex linkages between financial, fiscal, real,
and social risks and ensure effective risk management at all levels of society.
The recent experience underscores the importance of: systematic, proactive, and
integrated risk management by individuals, societies, and Governments to
prepare for adverse consequences of financial shocks; mainstreaming proactive
risk management into the growth and development agendas; establishing
contingency planning mechanisms to avoid unintended economic and social
consequences of crisis management policies and building a better capacity to
analyze complex linkages and feedback loops between financial, sovereign, real
and social risks; maintaining fiscal room; and creating well-designed social
protection policies that target the vulnerable, while ensuring fiscal
sustainability.
However, at the origin of the Fiscal Crisis of the State –to borrow the title of a James O’
Connor book very popular in the nineteen eighties- , there is not the lack of
care in management of public finance and the little resistance to pressure
groups claiming shares of public funds. The European fiscal crisis of the State
has much deeper roots:
a) Since 1830 (when,
according to Angus Madison’s life-long painstaking statistical work, India and
China had 43% of world GDP) , Europe and North America grew at very sustained
rate, whilst the rest of world continued to stagnate around mere substance
level (as it had done for millennia)
because the key to technological progress in mechanics, electricity and other
forms of power was in the hands of a very few group of countries. This changed during
the nineteen nineties when due the Information Technology and the improved
level of education in emerging countries, the monopoly was broken.
b) In parallel, since
1830 or thereabout, political power and colonialism implied a real annual
transfer of resources estimated by the late economist Enzo Grilli (who worked
both for the IMF and the World Bank) of some $ 20-30 billion p.a. . The
transfer was made almost entirely through terms of trade favorable to North
America and Europe, as I documented in a book published way back in 1967.
These two determinants fueled growth and allowed income redistribution within North America and
Europe (as well Australia, Japan and New Zealand). But they have been a
phenomenon that after nearly two century has lost its steam and more lately has
vanished. Thus, a major world economy structural adjustment is taking place
since the mid nineteen nineties. It entails the world structure of production,
income, investment, savings. North America and the countries of the antipodes
have shown great ability in adjusting to the new context. Within the European
Union , and more significantly within the euro zone, countries have shown very
different capabilities to make the necessary changes, even because they welfare
states had evolved in very differing ways in the last two centuries.
When Europe and North America (and a few other
counties) had the monopoly of technical progress and, consequently high growth
rates, welfare systems provided insurance against
risks of becoming unemployed, disabled, poor, old and the like. Philosophically these welfare
systems rested on social welfare theory, a consequence-based (or
consequentialist) approach geared toward formulating and implementing
corrective actions to mitigate market failures and other
societal imperfections.
Each
pension and welfare system is the result of a delicate balance of economic,
social, and political power. Worldwide, pension systems are broadly classified
as based on defined contributions or defined benefits, funded or unfunded, and
actuarial or non-actuarial. A more specific taxonomy is used to depict the
principal features of Western European pension and welfare systems as they were
originally designed:
·
In
terms of eligibility there are
universal systems where, subject to certain criteria, all citizens (or
residents) of a country are entitled to basic welfare and pension coverage,
often based on a flat rate element complemented by an earnings-related
component, and particularistic, occupation-based systems where welfare and
pension mechanisms are tied to recipients’ status, normally their occupation.
·
In
terms of financing there are systems
financed almost entirely by general taxation and there
are those
financed mostly by contribution from workers (as future retirees) and their
employers. More important, some welfare and systems are based on pay- as- you- go mechanisms where
current benefits are paid out of current revenues (contributions) and the
general exchequer, while others rely on funded mechanisms that pay benefits
using proceeds from capital accumulation.
·
In
terms of administration, some systems are
centrally run by the public service and some are highly decentralized to other
public or semi public
institutions, often operated as autonomous agencies under boards and management
committees representing workers and employers..
FOUR
PATTERNS OF WELFARE AND PENSION SYSTEMS IN
EUROPE
Eligibility
|
Benefits
|
Financing
|
Administration
|
Scandinavian
Countries
|
|||
Universalistic
|
High
|
General taxation
|
Central Government
|
Ireland, United Kingdom
|
|||
Universalistic
|
Low
(but can be increased)
|
Taxation and contribution
|
Central Government
|
Benelux,
France, Germany, Italy
|
|||
Occupational
|
High
|
Payroll contribution
|
Intermediate bodies
|
Portugal and Spain
|
|||
Corporatist
|
High
(only for certain categories)
|
Taxation and
contribution
|
Intermediate bodies
|
Most Western European welfare and pension
systems have evolved into mixed systems with varying elements of all these
features and of defined contribution and defined benefit, funded and unfunded,
and actuarial and non-actuarial components. Pension reforms in Sweden and Italy
show how a universal system (Sweden) and a particularistic, occupation-based
system (Italy) have evolved into mixed systems and changed, nearly in parallel,
their pay as you go defined benefit pillars into partly funded actuarial and
defined contribution pillars. Significant institutional differences across
countries will likely remain important for the foreseeable future, but gradual
reforms towards NdcNDC (Notional Defined Contribution) couple
with a funded pillar could go a long way towards reducing these differences and
even pave the road towards a EU pension system with a growing private leg)
based on individual pension savings plans). The NDC system has
been pioneered in Italy and Sweden: pension payments are based not on salary
received in the last few years of work or throughout the working life , but on
the workers and employers contributions to the pension system, updated on the
basis of formula related to GDP and cost of living growth (this is way it
called ‘notional’)
In almost all countries of the EU, the bulk of the
welfare expenditure concern the pension systems. Many systems where conceived
when ‘the risk’ of becoming old were quite small because life expectancy was
short; thus, pensions were thought as an insurance against such a risk for the
few that reached old age, to be paid by the many who never became old. Over
the next few decades the EU in general and Western Europe in particular will
face a significant acceleration in ageing
due to the ‘baby boom’
generation reaching retirement age, continued
increases in life expectancy, and decreases in fertility, especially since the
early nineteen seventies . Together the
large cohort reaching retirement age and rising life expectancy will cause a
doubling of Western Europe’s old age
dependency ratio (defined here as the number of people 65 and older as a
percentage of those 15–64). In 2000 this ratio was just over 25 percent; by
2050 it will be more than 50 percent. Even if the
average fertility rate were to gradually increase,
it would not be sufficient to counter a projected reduction in the EU
population starting around 2020. As a result,
public spending on pensions is projected to increase considerably.
Until
a few years ago only demographers and economists were seriously
concerned by these developments. But now public perceptions of their
implications for pension systems are widening and deepening in the civil
society as a whole as well as among politicians.. Because most
existing systems are public ‘pay- as -you –go’
schemes (i.e the current working generation pay the checks for
the retirees),
a majority of Western Europeans are taking pessimistic views of their future
public pension entitlements and of the difficulties they will have in living on
foreseeable retirement incomes
An obvious policy response to rising life
expectancy would be to raise the retirement age
which —typically
stands
at 65 in Western
European countries. But few people stay in the labor market until the statutory
age, with most retiring between the ages of 56 and
60. On average, Western Europeans spend twenty years in
retirement, up from thirteen years in the
1960s. Another obvious response to rising life expectancy would be to develop
fully funded pension pillars, private or public . But
the heavy
burden of employer and employee contributions to ‘pay -as -you -go
schemes’
leaves little room for the savings required for funding, especially during the
transition phase. Also the NDC systems
are ‘pay as you go’ for several years to come , but they have an ‘automatic
pilot’ in their design whereby in a couple of decades pension payments ought to
be in line with contributions.
Over the past fifteen
years, many
Western European countries
have embarked on pension reform, and the related challenges have led to lively
debate. Recently a few Ggovernments
– most importantly the German and the British Governments – have indicated the
intention of proposing to Parliament a gradual increase of
the statutory pension age from 65 to 67 years of age. Italy has
introduced a system whereby the pension age will be periodically adjusted to
changes in general life expectancy of the population.
A
common but rarely studied philosophical trend underlies the shift from the
social welfare theory to the contractual approach in pensions and other aspects of welfare. Whereas the social welfare theory approach
focuses on outcomes—the consequences of policies and programs—the contractual
approach seeks to get “institutions’
right” through appropriate procedures where, given ethical constraints, rights
protection, and fair rules of the game, individual are free to pursue their own
ends. In pension and welfare policies
this implies an emphasis on greater freedom of choice about contribution levels
and future benefits, retirement age, risk diversification between two or more
pillars, and the coverage ratio of retirement benefits relative to income in
the last few years of working life. This also entail s more
extended private participation by individuals, families and corporations in
providing welfare through private efforts (ei participation to private pension
plans and to complementary health programs as well as to unemployment
insurance). In Italy, there are some 700 different pension funds; there a clear
need for concentration and merger to reach a number similar to those in other
EU countries (rarely more than 50 per country) so as to provide for larger,
stronger and more diversified protection. Also recently, in November 2013, the
Italian Economic Club (Club dell’Economia) awarded to the former Minister of
Labour and Social Affairs a special prize for the best economic idea in many
years: the introduction of a compulsory unemployment insurance because the
country did not have one and unemployment allowances were very low and last
only a few months. In the field of health, in all EU countries is, albeit to
different degrees, how to improve efficiency and how to shift from curative to
preventing care: it is appalling that nearly two third of health research and
development expenditures concerns diseases related to the last six months of
life.
The EU is generally criticized for not moving forward
fast enough in the welfare systems. If this applies to the attempts to
harmonize long established systems, such a strategy would be beating the wrong
bush because, as shown above, the differences mirror very profound historical
path; society are as ‘path dependent’ as individuals . A more promising route
would be to try to attempt to learn from
each other: the NDC pension system is a good example because it was initiated,
separately , by two very different countries (Italy and Sweden) and now is
applied , in various versions and at different stages, by a dozen EU countries.
Many EU countries have to learn from labour market reforms applied in Austria
and Germany. Overall harmonization, however, would be beneficial in two areas:
i) general financial constraints and ii) the avoidance of discrimination (i.e
by gender, sexual orientation).
The road to change the UE welfare model (and its diverse
systems) is likely to be long and hard. But it is likely to be successful if
the EU follows a strategy along the lines summarized above.
Nessun commento:
Posta un commento